Vol.
63, No. 4
Toshihiko IWAMA
The urban elite in Leeds during the Industrial Revolution, 1780-1820:
from notables to middle class
Although the development of the British middle class from early modern
times to the nineteenth century has been much studied, not enough is
known about its transformation during the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries. The object of this paper is to examine the change from domination
by the notables to domination by the middle class in Leeds, a northern
industrial and commercial town.
In eighteenth-century Leeds,
the urban elite, who controlled the Leeds Corporation and monopolised
the post of Justice of the Peace, maintained the structure of social
control in local areas through paternalism. In this paper this structure
is called 'domination by the notables'.
Through social and economic
change in Leeds from the end of the eighteenth century, the urban elite
‹ô merchants and manufacturers with a laissez-faire spirit, and professionals
who valued respectability ‹ô were at the centre of a middle class economic
relationship. After 1810, the domination by notables started to change
as a result of both conflicts among sects and parties, and opposition
to paternalistic policies which occurred in the Improvement Commission,
the vestry and the workhouse. In response, the urban elite began to
support an equilibrium between the old policy of paternalism and laissez-faire.
From the 1820s, the urban
elite began to form middle class social relationships, including shared
experiences and consciousness in a top-down manner, through activities
in voluntary societies. The urban elite who had been dominated by the
notables underwent a change and started to rebuild the structure of
social control, based on these new middle class social relationships.
Domination by the middle class appeared as an alternative to paternalistic
domination by the notables.
Tomoko HASHINO
Power-looms and the factory system: the relation between production
systems and technology choice in the silk textile industry in Kiryu
in the 1910s
Recent studies have clarified some special features regarding the introduction
of power-looms, especially in pre-war Japan. One of the more important
findings was the close relationship between particular production systems
and technologies, for example the factory system and power-looms and
the putting-out system and hand-looms.
The purpose of this paper
is to investigate the above relationship in the silk textile industry
on the basis of the hypothesis that the factors leading to the introduction
of power-looms are independent from those leading to the introduction
of the factory system. Kiryu is one of the oldest silk textile industry
districts in Japan. In the early Meiji period (1870s-80s) it showed
a positive response to the introduction of new foreign technology, such
as the batten and the Jacquard machine, and helped to spread them to
other areas. But Kiryu was slower than other areas in introducing power-
looms. The putting-out system was widely adopted in Kiryu and had a
long history. It has been assumed that this acted as an obstacle to
the introduction of power-looms.
In the 1910s, there were
four types of factory in Kiryu: factories with power-looms only, factories
with hand-looms only, those with both, and those with none, which were
often called orimoto (clothiers). Neither the production systems nor
the technology dramatically changed in Kiryu in the 1910s; however,
some factories began to introduce power-looms.
There were some reasons that
promoted the adoption of the factory system. OJT (on-the-job-training),
which played a role in maintaining the quality of goods, was an important
reason in Kiryu in the 1910s. As past studies point out, institutional,
technological and market factors were other reasons that promoted the
introduction of power-looms there. While both electrification and the
establishment of domestic and local power-loom suppliers were very important,
it appears that the change in raw material from raw silk to rayon in
the 1920s was the decisive factor in accelerating mechanization. The
fact that hand-loom factories have often been categorized as "manufacture"
has been a controversial issue among historians. But we must recognize
the significance of their role in controlling workers and turning them
into a skilled labor force.
Takeshi TANIZAWA
The overland trade route between the Baltic Sea and the North Sea during
the golden era of the German Hansa: Lubeck - Oldesloe - Hamburg
In the sixteenth century,
the Sound Waterway became the prime trade route connecting the Baltic
Sea and the North Sea; before that however, an overland route between
Lubeck and Hamburg served as the main link between the two Seas. This
overland route included a river route connecting Lubeck and Oldesloe,
a small city situated between the two Hansa cities. It has been said
that it was this overland route that sustained the east-west trade of
the Hanseatic League before the sixteenth century. The purpose of this
article is to outline the scale and structure of the trade carried out
over this route.
An analysis of the Lubeck
Customs (Pfundzoll) Register of 1368 shows that Oldesloe was its main
trading partner both for exports and imports, the volume far exceeding
trade with major Baltic cities such as Danzig, Riga, or Stockholm. Imports
via Oldesloe came mainly from the North Sea and cloth was easily the
major item. Lubeck's exports to Oldesloe consisted chiefly of goods
such as butter, wax, herring, copper and flax, all of which were important
items in the Hanseatic trade area. Most of these goods were transported
by skippers of small boats who plied back and forth between Lubeck and
Oldesloe.
From an analysis of the Pfundzoll
Register of 1368, we can confirm that the overland route connecting
Lubeck and Hamburg via Oldesloe transported many, if not most, of the
goods traded between the Baltic Sea and the North Sea. Before the sixteenth
century, this route played an essential role in linking the two Seas,
in terms of both the volume, and the contents, of trade.
Seiichiro YOSHIZAWA
Compulsory contributions and urban control in Tianjin in the late Qing
period (1858-1911)
It has often been pointed out that levies of many kinds of compulsory
contribution began in the era of the New Policy of the late Qing period.
Most scholars have concluded that such contributions were collected
in order to raise funds for the New Policy and pay the indemnities to
the foreign countries. On the other hand, some scholars think that the
imposition of these contributions signified a fiscal shift from taxes
on agricultural surpluses to taxes on commercial profits. But if these
interpretations are correct, why were contributions also imposed on
the lower classes in urban society, who had little ability to pay?
This paper tries to answer
this question by inquiring into several categories of urban resident
in Tianjin: stall keepers, rickshaws pullers, and prostitutes. They
paid compulsory contributions in order to gain permission to engage
in their particular trades, which were regarded as a cause of disorder
and crime in urban society. Meanwhile, by levying contributions, the
police were able to keep a watch on these people and to preserve social
order.
The compulsory contributions
imposed on ordinary houses and shops can be understood in the same way.
To pay contributions was to gain the sanction of the police. This was
a way of constructing social order in the absence of any concept of
the freedom of residence or business. In the late Qing period, people
poured into the open port cities in search of work and the influx of
population upset the balance of urban society. Social control by levying
compulsory contributions was introduced to deal this situation.