Vol.
66, No. 2
Jaeho KIM
The finances of the sovereign and the formation of a 'tax state': a
comparison between Korea and Japan (1868-1910)
This is a comparative study of the important problems posed by the imperial
finances in Korea and Japan during the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries, when both states were trying to form a modern financial system,
in other words, a 'tax state'. Both had to overcome the 'doctrine of
imperial land' (the notion that all lands in the country belong to the
sovereign) .
Korea applied the doctrine
of imperial ownership of all land up to the time of the last land survey,
never developing doctrines and institutions to justify levying taxes
on citizens once their rights to land ownership had been recognised.
Japan, however, severed the relation between the king's sovereign power
over land and the right to ownership of that land.
'The doctrine of imperial
land' was replaced by the principle that taxes were the expenses paid
by the members of the national community for the upkeep of the community.
In this regard, it can be said that the concept of taxation in the Japanese
Imperial Constitution had advanced one step further than the sovereign's
tax of Korea. Even so, the Japanese system failed to establish the reciprocal
right of citizens to agree to the levying of taxes.
Masahiro OGIYAMA
Why were Japanese agricultural laborers not forced to work against their
will? A case study of Hatta village in the Sennan district of Osaka
prefecture, 1879-1887
In the late nineteenth century, Japanese agricultural laborers had normally
borrowed so much from their employers that they were entirely dependent
on them. Despite this, the employers were unable to use the services
of such laborers whenever they wanted. Evidence of why this was so can
be found through examining the case of the Tsukamoto family, a rich
farming family of Hatta village in Sennan, Osaka.
Many Hatta inhabitants were
debtors of the Tsukamoto, and such people were hired by them as daily
agricultural laborers. But villagers indebted to the family, including
agricultural laborers, would often band together to demand debt reduction.
This makes it clear that if the family had tried to hire day laborers
whenever it suited them by using threats about debt payment, they would
have been considered hostile by the inhabitants. However, since the
head of the family was also the headman of the village, the Tsukamoto
also had the responsibility of preserving order. They were therefore
unable to use the services of day labourers whenever it suited them
for fear that village inhabitants would disrupt the peace.
Yuanbao XIONG
The water supply business and 'waterways' in Beijing, 1644-1949
This article uses documents from the Niida Collection on contracts for
water supplies in Beijing to focus on groups of water carriers from
Shandong. For centuries these people migrated to Beijing and engaged
in the sale of water for domestic use. Information on them is scarce,
but their numbers are calculated to have amounted to around ten thousand
men in the late Qing and early Republican eras. The paper also considers
the urbanization process from the Ming and Qing dynasties onwards, and
the migration of village farmers into the city.
Beijing suffered from a serious
water shortage. From the late Ming and early Qing, migrants from Shandong
supplied water to residents and eventually competition led to the formation
of different territories, the development of exclusive monopolies, and
the formation of 'waterways', an order and rights concerning the handling
of users' capital to pay for water supplies. The negative social image
of water carriers was a result of the gap between their self-imposed
order and the more liberated economic and social order of the city.
While they made an important contribution to the everyday life of the
city, they remained of marginal status and were never accepted as full
inhabitants.
Hidenori MISHINA
Economic change in farming districts and the development of peasant
management in modern north China: an area study of Ding county, Hebei
province
The purpose of this
paper is to examine economic change in farming districts in modern north
China, focusing on the shift in the relative importance of farming and
off-farm occupations in different peasant households.
After the construction of
the Beijing-Hankou railroad in Ding county in 1900, in one particular
area that was both situated along the railroad and suitable for cotton
cultivation, peasant households began to use their male labor force
to produce cotton handicrafts for sale. In other areas, however, geographic
and geological conditions resulted in the persistence of biannual triple
cropping.
Later, the demand for cotton
textiles led more and more peasant households in the former area to
concentrate on cotton handicrafts, to the extent of cutting down their
cultivated acreage. Accordingly, it became increasingly difficult for
them to give up cotton handicrafts even during recessions. That was
the reason why American strains of cotton, which could not be used for
handicraft production, were cultivated not in the former area, but in
the latter ones, after irrigation. In other words, each peasant household
decided its course based on its own existing reproduction structure.
This is why the process of commercialization in rural modern north China
exhibited regional differences.