Vol.
69, No. 2
Susumu HIRAI
The March Revolution and settlement regulations in the village societies
of northwest Germany
This article examines settlement regulations in one Hanoverian province
(Provinz Osnabrück) during the 1840s and 1850s in order to investigate
changes in rural social order and autonomy.
Before 1848 there was Pauperismus
(great poverty) among the rural lower classes of the region, particularly
among the Heuerleute (landless cottagers) who rented cottages and land
from Bauern (farm holders). Traditionally, the state and village communities,
whose members were solely Bauern, exercised little control over these
renting relationships. However, when the Heuerleute began to riot and
petition in March 1848, the state attempted to mediate between them
and the Bauern. In October, the state and the provincial parliament
established a law governing the renting of cottages and land. According
to the law, village communities were expected to organize Heuerlings-commissionen
(local commissions) composed of both Bauern and Heuerleute members.
After 1848, under the supervision of the state, these commissions began
to monitor and control the Bauern who rented cottages and land to Heuerleute
families. Consequently, the March Revolution ended the early modern
form of Bauern autonomy via state intervention and the partial integration
of the landless cottagers.
Keishi SHIRATORI
The activities of the Bank of Japan as lender of last resort in the
1920s
The purpose of this article is to analyze the activities of the Bank
of Japan as lender of last resort (LLR) in the 1920s. During the crisis
of 1920 and the banking upheaval of 1922, the Bank of Japan faced an
outflow of specie as a result of the rapidly worsening balance of trade,
and therefore limited its relief financing. However, after the great
Kanto earthquake of 1923 it embarked on large-scale relief financing,
with government backing, in order to prevent a financial disaster. As
a result, the market stagnated from an excess of currency. Since there
was the additional issue of a possible return to the gold standard,
when the 1927 crash occurred the Bank of Japan made retrenchment its
priority and carried out more relief financing, particularly for the
larger banks. In short, the Bank of Japan's activities as LLR in this
period were regulated by the logic of the return to the gold standard.
Masafumi YOMODA
Interregional competition in the production of imitation Panama hats:
an institutional comparison of prewar Taiwan and Okinawa
Prewar Japan exported imitation Panama hats, which were produced mainly
in Taiwan and Okinawa. However, there were sharp differences between
the institutions organizing economic transactions in each region. This
paper analyzes the institutional differences, focusing mainly upon transaction
patterns between merchants and producers, trade associations, export
inspection systems, and institutions for improving production techniques.
The first difference is that
while producers in Okinawa were dominated by Japanese merchants with
relatively long-term gains in mind, those in Taiwan gradually became
independent of Japanese merchants and exported hats through Taiwanese
branches in Kobe. Second, while short-term transactions were predominant
in Taiwan because of frequent entries and exits by producers and merchants,
long-term transactions were predominant in Okinawa. Third, while the
short-term transactions in Taiwan led to short-sighted behavior, such
as the adulteration of products and the weakening of trade associations,
the long-term ones in Okinawa produced hats of improved quality, stronger
trade association, and good producing skills. In conclusion, institutions
in both Taiwan and Okinawa developed complementary relationships which
led to contrasting institutional combinations, causing differences in
performance. In addition, the implication is that the institutions adopted
in Taiwan and Okinawa reflected different economic traditions in China
and Japan respectively.
Mikito NAKASHIMA
The illegal partition of common land in the prefecture of the Drôme
during the French Revolution
From the autumn of 1792, there
were frequent disturbances in the rural communities of the Drôme
regarding the illegal division of common land (or lands held in common).
The purpose of this article is to examine the processes which led to
such illegal partitions and the social awareness of the peasantry of
the time.
Since the eve of the Revolution,
rural communities had wanted to divide not only common land which had
been seized by the feudal lord, but also that which had remained under
community control. They anticipated that the public authorities would
legalize partition. But when the law of October 11, 1792 cut off their
hopes by deferring partition, rural communities refused to obey, and
began a process of illegal partition through voluntary direct action.
In their eyes, this was a legitimate way of restoring social justice.
Even after the partition,
rural communities maintained traditional customs and rights of cultivation.
This indicates that the purpose behind the partition was not to create
the modern proprietary rights, but to increase communal and individual
income and to achieve a secure livelihood through the effective use
of common land.
Manabu OZEKI
Clothing consumption and the concepts of flow and stock: an analysis
of late-Meiji village surveys in Ibaraki prefecture
This article argues that before
World War I rural clothing consumption cannot be understood as a 'flow'
concept alone. An analysis of extant sonze (village surveys) in Ibaraki
prefecture reveals, firstly, that there were two different concepts
of 'consumption', and hence two different words and measures for it:
seisan (production) consumption and seikatsu (living) consumption. The
former consisted of the purchase of an item as well as home production,
and was measured from output data. The latter meant the daily use of
an item which was in stock. In this case the estimated use value was
probably calculated from the total amount of clothes in stock, and it
never corresponded to any 'flow' measures of clothing consumption. Secondly,
it seems that people at that time applied the concept of depreciation
to the household's clothing stock too. These findings have considerable
implications. First, we cannot estimate the peasants' standard of living
from 'flow' measures alone. Second, if the peasants' chief motive in
purchasing new clothes was to replace worn-out traditional kimono, then
it would not have been easy for western-style clothing to penetrate
the Meiji rural market. This interpretation is consistent with recent
studies in textile history.