Vol.
69, No. 4
<Conference report>
Kanji ISHII
The economic history of information: state, market, and enterprise
It is commonly acknowledged that modern capitalist society developed
as a result of the industrial revolution of the nineteenth century.
However, economists and historians have different views of the effect
which the recent revolution in information technology will have on this
society. The common theme of the seventy-first annual conference of
the Socio-Economic History Society, organized by Masaaki TAKASHIMA and
Kanji ISHII, was the analysis of the impact of electric communications
on society.
Kazuko FURUTA discussed how
the Chinese merchants of Shanghai in the latter half of the nineteenth
century obtained confidential information from colleagues from the same
province, though they obtained general information from the market.
Kazuhiro OMORI discussed how Japanese medium and small-sized producers
in the interwar period obtained information about foreign markets from
trade associations that were supported by the government.
Commenting on these two reports,
Kaoru SUGIHARA observed that the flow of economic information in the
United Kingdom was quite different from that of China and Japan. Nobuyuki
FUJII remarked that the flow of confidential information was closely
related to the type of market economy.
<Conference
report>
Kazuko FURUTA
Information and institutions in economic history: Chinese merchants
and information
This article discusses approaches to a wide variety of historical markets
in terms of incompleteness and asymmetry of information. After examining
general features of information, it classifies information into two
types. Type A consists of 'on spot information', which includes tacit
knowledge that nonmembers of a certain club or community have difficulty
acquiring, and mutually shared understandings about the basic frameworks
for carrying out transactions. Since users have difficult ascertaining
the quality of information in advance, certain devices or institutions
to certify the quality of the information are necessary. Among Chinese
merchants in modern East Asia, the kebang network, made up of individuals
from the same native place, was such a device, although the specific
institutional form it took varied from society to society.
Type B, on the other hand,
consists of general market information such as price, volume of arrival
and stock, exchange rates etc. Since there was relatively free access
to such information, its prompt utilization was also critical in the
Shanghai market. In each transaction both types played important roles.
The variation of markets in history therefore derives from the fluctuating
balance of these two types of information.
<Conference
report>
Kazuhiro OMORI
Overseas information gathering activities between World Wars I and II
During the Meiji era (1868-1912),
the government played an important role in obtaining the knowledge and
information necessary for small and medium-sized businesses. However,
in the period between the two major World Wars, it was the small and
medium-sized businesses themselves that took the initiative in gathering
relevant information from overseas. Trade organizations in particular
played active roles, with some local trade and manufacturers' associations
being established to represent the then major exports, such as cotton
fabrics, silks (both natural and artificial fabrics), knitwear and ceramic
ware, in areas where these industries were thriving.
In the ceramic industry,
for example, the industry's trade organization is known to have played
roles in settling market upheavals and trade disputes following the
Wars, and in helping their members' business development. This organization
also conducted product inspections and other activities concerning product
quality control. It is very likely that these exertions, coupled with
publicizing their industry's products, contributed to an increase in
exports. Further, during the period between the World Wars, a number
of small and medium-sized ceramic exporters, nurtured by the trade organization,
grew to develop informational activities of their own that promoted
local business as a whole.
Yoshiteru TAKEI
Child and juvenile labour in the English cotton industry
The English cotton industry
relied considerably upon child and juvenile labour throughout most of
its existence. Although at first each mule spinner employed just one
little piecer under the subcontract system, after the 1830s, as a result
of both the enlargement and the increased speed of the mule, one spinner
employed three or four little piecers. These were children and juveniles,
who were skilled and hard-working but received well below the adult
wage. As soon as they became eligible for the adult wage, they were
replaced by children who were old enough to work. Almost the same story
is applicable to the spinning process.
From the beginning of the
twentieth century there were repeated reports of a shortage of juvenile
labour. What was the cause? First, there were the poor labour conditions
for juveniles; second came the fact that the juvenile labour market
had changed to a seller's market. Previously the cotton industry was
the only trade in Lancashire that furnished juveniles and children with
employment. However, in the twentieth century, employment opportunities
appeared in other fields such as the distributive trades, furniture
making and miscellaneous metal trades. The preferences of both children
and their parents therefore shifted away from the cotton trade.
Masahiko AKATSU
The air pollution problem in the British Industrial Revolution: the
enactment of the Smoke Nuisance Abatement Act of 1821
The Industrial Revolution
in Britain led to widespread pollution in the form of factory smoke,
and raised the issue of social relief. Scholars have argued that the
Smoke Nuisance Abatement Act of 1821 resulted from the efforts of just
one public-spirited politician. In this paper, however, through examining
parliamentary debates on this issue, we analyze how politicians, landlords,
and industrialists viewed the damage caused by air pollution, how they
developed a framework for redress, and how they interwove their interests
into the act.
Landowners, and even the
manufacturers who were responsible, recognized that air pollution caused
damage to property. For this reason, the act was promoted by landowners
and even some industrial capitalists, although they are normally regarded
as opponents of smoke regulation. As the smoke prevention technologies
of the time might be a source of profit for manufacturers, the act of
1821 did not conflict with their business principles. The owners of
private property were merely seeking redress for the damage that they
had suffered. It was not until the 1840's that more interventionist
legislation aimed at helping urban laborers was contemplated.